(PAMBAZUKA) Zimbabwe’s land reform is common sense
COMMENT - This article is from the pro-MDC PAMBAZUKA NEWS, and although the standard issue MDC policies are suggested, the core of the article addresses the fact that Black Zimbabweans have been doing the actual business of farming all along.Zimbabwe’s land reform is common sense
Grasian Mkodzongi
2010-03-11, Issue 473
Zimbabwe’s land issue has generated unprecedented debate nationally and internationally, largely polarised between supporters of radical land reform and supporters of market-oriented reforms, writes Grasian Mkodzongi. While it is ‘undeniable’ that Mugabe used land reform ‘to boost his political legitimacy’, how can one ‘justify the continued existence of a dualistic land ownership structure decades after independence, in a country whose struggle for liberation crystallised around the land issue?’, Mkodzongi asks.
Zimbabwe’s land issue has generated unprecedented debates both within and outside the country. The debates, which followed the dramatic occupations of white farms by rural peasants in the late 1990s, are generally polarised between those who support radical land reform and those who support market-orientated reforms. The former stand accused of supporting Mugabe’s regime while the latter are generally maligned as neo-colonialists running a smear campaign against Zanu PF.
An unfortunate outcome of these polarities has been the trivialisation of the land issue; land occupations have been depicted as simple acts of political gimmickry; landless peasants who occupied these farms have been branded as agents of agrarian and environmental destruction, and are often considered to be in service to the ‘evil’ regime of Robert Mugabe.
Some academics have even gone as far as branding the whole process of land occupations, and the violence associated with it, as an apocalyptic end of modernity. In academia, supporters of radical land reform are generally in the minority; this has made it extremely difficult to challenge the current neo-liberal orthodoxy, which dominates land and agrarian reform policy making in many African countries. The few scholars, who have openly challenged the ‘hostile’ neo-liberal approach to argue for radical land reform, including Sam Moyo, Paris Yeros, and Mamood Mamdani, have often been accused of colluding with Mugabe’s undemocratic regime.
That Mugabe opportunistically used the land issue to boost his political legitimacy is an undeniable fact. Indeed, the country’s collective memory was conveniently manipulated to fit a set political agenda under guise of the ‘Third Chimurenga’ project. However, juxtaposed to Mugabe’s gerrymandering and manipulation of historical memory is a reality that many critics of Mugabe have so far failed to address. How can one justify the continued existence of a dualistic land ownership structure decades after independence, in a country whose struggle for liberation crystallised around the land issue? How could such an unjust and medieval property ownership structure be permanently sustained in a country where 60 per cent of the population depends on land for their livelihoods?
Another paradox of Zimbabwe’s independence is the extent to which white farmers emerged unscathed by the raging fires of the liberation struggle. Zimbabwe’s negotiated settlement, which led to independence in 1980, left white farmers constitutionally protected. Like Royal game, they held the entire nation at ransom thanks to Lord Carrington, who secured their private property and political rights before handing over a poisoned state to the blacks.
Mugabe’s reconciliatory rhetoric that dominated the early years of independence led to the general belief among White Rhodesians that independence was ‘business as usual’, with many whites continuing to enjoy colonial era privileges and existing in white enclaves. In the so-called ‘new Zimbabwe’, white commercial farmers continued to dominate the commercial farming sector, a key strategic sector given the largely agrarian nature of Zimbabwe’s economy. This gave them leverage over government policy, which they used to secure their large estates from potential forceful acquisition.
Above all, they voted for Ian Smith’s exclusively white Rhodesian Front political party; a mockery of the ideals of a ‘united nation’ propounded by Mugabe’s nationalist administration. On the other hand, the peasantry in remote rural locations continued to eke out a living on degraded patches of barren land, waiting for the ‘promised’ land that was at the core of the liberation struggle. However, such promises failed to materialise; macro-economic policies favoured landed capitalists and black elites based in cities that generally enjoyed the patronage of senior politicians. A result of the above was that most of the land ‘recovered’ by the government was diverted to Zanu PF loyalists through patronage networks.
Why then do many people decry the land invasions if history shows that peasants were the major losers at independence? Given Zimbabwe’s history, one wonders why white farmers were allowed to sell land back to the government after 1980 instead of helping to contribute to the land reform programme as a form of reparation for the violence and plunder suffered by many Africans during the colonial era. After all, most of the large farms were acquired under unjust and illegal terms. Justice would have been better served if after securing independence, Mugabe’s government had thrown away the 1979 Lancaster House Constitution in favour of a just constitution based on the country’s historical experiences. Why hang on to a constitution, which promoted the interests of the very people that supported the wanton destruction of African livelihoods, and the merciless bombing of civilians at Nyadzonya, which to this day have never been fully accounted for.
Actually there is a timeline. At independence in 1980, much of the existing situation was frozen for 10 years through the Lancaster House Constitution. By 1990, whites would no longer be overrepresented in parliament, etc. However, in 1989, the Berlin Wall fell and everything changed. The ANC in South Africa asked the ZANU-PF to go slow on land reform until the ANC had concluded it's negotiations with the apartheid government. In 1994, Nelson Mandela came to power in South Africa. Only 3 years later, in 1997, the New Labour government of Tony Blair came to power, and officially and unilaterally reneged on it's obligation to fund the Willing Buyer, Willing Seller Program, through Clare Short's letter to minister Kumbirai Kangai. This set the stage for the Fast Track Land Reform Programme. And the rest is history. - MrK
This would have allowed an unfettered land reform programme that was cognisant of our past and righted the wrongful misdeeds of a few. Instead, a dithering elitist government failed to deliver one of the most precious prizes of our independence: The land.
See above. - MrK
For if so many people died at Chimoio, Nyadzonya and in many operational zones, how could their souls rest in peace if independence only resulted in the perpetuation of the status quo? Why could we as a sovereign nation in the interest of morality and justice not say to Britain and other world nations that so many people died for this land, all they want is a fair share of their heritage?’ Is that not a modest demand given our history? Mugabe’s rhetoric on land should be given serious consideration, however he should also be held accountable for failing to stand up against neo-colonial tactics that led to unnecessary delays in recovering stolen property and for presiding over a patrimonial system which helped to marginalise a large section of the population. Much of the socialist rhetoric that appears in the country’s Transitional Development Plan (TDP) was never put into practice, instead an ahistorical Land Reform and Resettlement Programme (LRRP) was adopted. This policy was much influenced by Britain and other agents of western capitalism left too much leverage with white farmers who were able to dictate the pace of the land reform programme, and in the process, distort land markets to their advantage. The result was that the LRRP was too expensive to sustain for a postcolonial government with limited resources. Moreover, those who were ‘chosen’ for resettlement were given land unfavorable to agriculture with limited support in terms of infrastructure and farming inputs. Mugabe’s government, like its colonial predecessor, was reluctant to extend full property rights to the beneficiaries of the LRRP and instead opted to allow resettled farmers to occupy land under insecure permits while at the same time allowing white farmers to continue owning their land on a more secure freehold basis. This perpetuated a system of insecure property rights in communal areas that had been created during the colonial era within the so-called ‘communal tenure’ system.
An analysis of the arguments against radical land reform reveals a chronic failure by both journalists and academics to provide a balanced overview of the Zimbabwean land issue; the causal factors of landlessness steeped in the country’s history are often ignored. There is a tendency to confuse the land issue with Mugabe’s political expediency and in the process the baby is thrown away with the bath water. The genuine need for land, which is reflected in many rural areas across the country, is simply dismissed as Mugabe’s political posturing. What is often forgotten is that not very long ago millions of Africans were deliberately disenfranchised by a system of state managed repression, segregation and violence. It is these masses that sacrificed their lives and livelihoods to liberate the country and it is these masses that have the moral right to claim back their land. This legitimate need to right the historical wrongs should never be confused with Zanu PF’s attempts to manipulate history for its own selfish interests.
What is also deeply disturbing about those who have argued against land invasions is their total disregard for the views of the poor and marginalised peasants who invaded these farms. On the rare occasions when peasants are featured in short documentaries or academic articles, they are often depicted as barbaric savages attacking white farmers and ruining productive farms.
In contrast, white farmers have generally been given positive media coverage in the west – sentimental testimonials telling stories of loss and ruin, agricultural equipment destroyed and wildlife poached. These stories are often accompanied by graphic images of dead wild animals, especially endangered species like rhinos, elephants etc.
This ‘sadistic’ imagery has generated sympathy for white farmers, by portraying them as hard working people, who became victims of Robert Mugabe’s ‘evil regime’. The plight of many rural farmers who have struggled to survive since the country was liberated decades ago is generally overlooked. They have no one to tell their stories of survival to and local ‘native’ intellectuals, generally far removed from the village, have failed to inform the world about the peasant’s precarious existence: Landlessness, water shortages and disease.
What is often suggested in the studies of fly past researchers is the notion that black peasants have an inherent lack of basic environmental knowledge and that they are incapable of feeding themselves. Across Europe, ignorance about the historical background to Zimbabwe’s land issue among ordinary people runs deep; remarks about how the Zimbabwe government allowed unskilled rural farmers to occupy farms are commonplace. The current food shortages facing the country are simply blamed on incompetent peasants taking over white farms.
It has become fashionable to project Zimbabwe as ‘a bread basket’ before the land invasions and a ‘basket case’ after land invasions. This has helped to support the assumption that without white farmers the country could not feed itself. What is often not mentioned is that the white farmer in Africa is generally an administrator; he does not physically grow crops himself.
His black troops produce on his behalf. However he gets the lion’s share of the profits because he controls the means of production. Moreover, it is easily forgotten that in the early years of colonial occupation in the 1890s, European settlers in Rhodesia survived on grain produced by Africans until The British South Africa Company (BSAC) deliberately destroyed a booming African agriculture in favour of promoting European agriculture after the so called ‘gold rush’ proved to be largely false. Against all odds, Africans have been feeding themselves even during the depression years of the 1930s when the colonial government introduced the Maize Control Act, which helped to distort the grain market in order to protect European farmers.
Apart from the above, there is another argument based on neo-liberal thinking, which says that land reform was supposed to be carried out in an orderly way in order to harness ‘white skills’. This, it is argued, would protect the productive potential of these farms. The question is why didn’t these white farmers share their skills before the onset of the land invasions? How can one account for the poverty and dislocation of many farm workers who lost their livelihoods once a farmer decided they were no longer needed after many years of hard labour with minimum remuneration?
This argument is also based on a false assumption that black farmers cannot grow crops without white supervision. Most Large Scale Commercial Farms (LSCF) have historically relied on black labour. If LSCF are largely run by black workers who with time have acquired advanced technical skills to operate farm machinery, supervise the large scale growing of commercial crops including tobacco and wheat, why then can blacks fail to do the same for themselves if given the land and the support required to run successful agricultural enterprises?
The image of the black farmer as a permanent subsistence farmer has become part of the official discourse about land and agrarian reform simply because for many decades black farmers have not been given the chance to invest in productive agriculture. It’s a historical fact that white agricultural success was based on expensive state subsidies, access to cheap labour and extension services, which allowed them to make profits even during the difficult years of economic stagnation. Such services were not accessible to black farmers who had to make do with very little financial and technical support from central government.
And active obstruction, like the Maize Control Act - as in Zambia too. - MrK
While it is true that land invasions did impact on agricultural production; critics of the programme have based their arguments on emotions rather than facts. Since the land invasions took place, no significant longitudinal study based on empirical research has been carried out to justify these arguments. Nobody knows to what extent the land invasions have impacted on agricultural production across the country. Moreover in trying to access such impacts, one has to take into account climatic factors like recurring droughts, which have historically affected agricultural production. Simplistic arguments biased against the peasantry have led to the trivialisation of an issue that is of paramount importance to Zimbabwe culturally, historically and economically. For land is not only the resource we have in abundance, it’s the only resource that sustains three quarters of the Zimbabwean population.
Given the above, land invasions were inevitable and necessary to ensure peasants ‘got a piece of the cake’. Of course one cannot expect such a radical programme to take place without any form of disruption. While it’s painful in the short term, land invasions have helped a significant number of property-less peasants to not only recover land, but to enjoy a sense of restitution which has a healing effect given the country’s tortured history.
They also helped to break the monopoly of white farmers in commercial agriculture by opening up this key sector to black farmers.
Moreover recent research by World Bank economists has proven that large commercial farms are not very productive compared to family operated smallholder farms; they are also a source of political instability as our recent history has demonstrated. Breaking up large commercial farms in favour of more efficient smallholder entities makes economic sense and promotes political stability.
What the Zimbabwean government should do now is to stop dilly-dallying and extend full property rights to peasants settled under the A1 Scheme to provide security and incentives for agricultural investment.
And there I would completely disagree. Land is for use, not speculation, and giving the right to sell land to people without money is a recipy for disaster and corporate takeover through banks. - MrK
It should also offer financial and technical support for those farmers who want to venture into commercial farming. Such a process requires non-partisan support from all those who benefited from land reform. It also requires a mechanism to recover land from those who are hoarding unproductive farms. This could be achieved through a land audit and a policy restricting farm ownership to a ‘one person one farm’ basis.
Both points the MDC wants to pursue. Sorry, but no. There are better ways to help out New Farmers than to allow them to put their land up for sale. - MrK
If the above measures were implemented, Zimbabwe would lead the way as the only country in postcolonial Africa to implement the most radical transfer of property in the 21st century.
It is there already. Let's keep it that way and let's support the farmers who exist today. - MrK
It would set an example for Zimbabwe’s neighbours, South Africa and Namibia, which are still slumbering under the stupor of market-driven land reform, with the inevitable risk of political instability as mobs of marginalised peasants are likely to resort to violence to recover land.
BROUGHT TO YOU BY PAMBAZUKA NEWS
* Grasian Mkodzongi is an ecologist and PhD candidate at the Centre of African Studies (University of Edinburgh).
* Please send comments to editor@pambazuka.org or comment online at Pambazuka News.
Labels: GRASIAN MKODZONGI, LAND REFORM
6 Comments:
Funny how one camp accuses Pambazuka News of being "pro-MDC" while the other accuses us of being "pro-Mugabe" for publishing articles by Sam Moyo, Mahmood Mamdani and others. We are neither, we are pro the people of Zimbabwe in all their struggles and all their troubles. We also respect that there are differences of viewpoint - and Pambazuka News prides itself for providing space for political debate about the issues (but not for mud-slinging or name-calling).
Firoze Manji, Editor, Pambazuka News
A well articulated article on the Zimbabwe issue. Unfortunately a lot of neo-liberalist still refuse to see this very common sense land reform. The author should be applauded for this work.
Dear Firoze Manji of Pambazuka News,
I am honored that you are reading my blog. :)
The problem I have with the article are the policy prescriptions on the one hand, which come straight out of the MDC (a land audit just to make sure no one has more than one [much smaller than before - a few hundred hectares as opposed to thousands and even tens of thousands of hectares] of land).
And secondly, the insistence on title deeds, which are a sure fire way to hand land over to the bank. It is a given globally that 90% of all startup companies fail (venture capitalists take that into account) and to then allow startups to use their land as collateral ensures that 90% of the land ends up with the banks, who will then sell it on to people with the cash to buy it - major corporations and former land owners. Especially as those former land owners have received 'compensation' for for instance the UK or US.
The only thing that will change is that they then have a legitimate claim as they have legally bought the land from a bank.
The purpose of land redistribution is that the people of the country will use the land.
Having said this, the core of the article is that the author acknowledges that the ZANU-PF's policy of land redistribution is not only moral and ethical, but that it is an economic necessity, because it allows people to participate in the economy, instead of being impoverished bystanders such as unfortunately is still the case in Namibia (the world number one in economic inequality according to the GINI Index) and even South Africa.
Furthermore, there is no evidence that what is lacking Zimbabwe's New Farmers are title deeds. Nor is there evidence that the ownership of multiple farms is rampant or hampering economic productivity.
Rather, the state of the national currency (destroyed in 2002 by economic sanctions contained in ZDERA) and the unwillingness of the US and UK government to let go of economic sanctions are much greater obstacles.
This is what I mean - the inclusion of the MDC's demands for title deeds and a land audit seems gratuitous.
That's all. :)
By the way, great article.
Om,
A well articulated article on the Zimbabwe issue. Unfortunately a lot of neo-liberalist still refuse to see this very common sense land reform. The author should be applauded for this work.
What is great about this article are the home truths that blow away the mythology of the white farmer in Africa, and the mythologising of agriculture as something only white people can do.
Africans already do most or all of the farming, and the white farmer not much more than an administrator. They would be nowhere if they actually had to work their own farms.
Which is why the average family farm in the EU is 90 hectares, not hundreds of hectares.
And this is something that is never said in the mainstream media.
For almost a century, the myth that has been relentlessly pushed is that 'somehow' Africans can't farm, when in reality legislation had to be introduced to artificially make African farmers less able to make money from selling their crops. This happened not only in Zimbabwe as the article points out, but it also happened just across the border in Zambia, through the Maize Control Ordinance of 1935, and later the Cattle Control Board (1937), which set a limit on the prices at which African farmers could sell their produce.
In fact, the falsehood that Africans were 'bad farmers' because they used 'destructive' farming methods was used as an excuse to under pay them for their product, so they would produce less of it.
So this kind of propaganda has a long history. Quoting from David P. Vickery's excellent Black And White In Southern Zambia - The Tonga Plateau Economy and British Colonialism, 1890-1939, on the introduction of the Maize Control Ordinance (page 206):
C.S. Knight, who had replaced Murray as the member for Southern Province, had no hesitation in supporting the bill. Without such a measure "it will mean the elimination of the European farmer in the country, and I think we all, if not openly, have at heart the necessity for the European colonisation of this country."
At the Colonial Office, meanwhile, officials reacted with raised eyebrows to the draft legislation. One termed the plan "one of the most extraordinary schemes I have ever seen." J.A. Calder of the C.O. branded it "ostensibly... but not really fair" because its basic object was "maintenance of the European farmer at the expense of the natives." But the Northern Rhodesian Government permitted LegCo to consider and pass the bill before hearing the Colonial Office reaction. In informing the C.O. of this fact, C.R. Dundas, the Chief Secretary again raised the paternalist argument that even one-quarter of the market was "much above what they [the Africans] should supply if they are to conserve their land." Moreover said Dundas, the idea that Africans might supply one-half the supply was "quite impossible" and flatly predicted that their share would fall short of even the mandated 25 percent.
A Whitehall pointed out the absurdity of Dundas last argument, with its implication that the division was "completely unnecessary and put in presumably for ornamental purposes".
Continued...
"Just before deliveries commenced in May, the Board decided, ostensibly for the sake of convenience, to fix in advance the pay-out for African maize. Since it was unclear what the Board's final revenue would be, the price was pegged at "safe", low level.
Thus Africans who delivered directly to the Board's depots received 5s. per bag the first year and 6s. the next two... These prices fell considerably short (by about one-third in the first three years of the average value of African maize after sales, even given the market division. The difference was paid into a fund set side for price stabilisation and, eventually, African farming improvement.
On the basis of the calculations upon which the control was introduced, African deliveries for an average year were expected to be 25% of the total, around 58,000 bags. Final figures for teh 1936 crop, however, the first under Control, told a radically different story. African deliveries amounted to 234,000 bags, 42% of the total. Probably 75% or more of African production came from the Tonga Plateau. These results produced some red faces in government, to say the least.
Source: Black And White In Southern Zambia, by David P. Vickery
So these lies go back way to colonialism, and are not limited to Zimbabwe/Rhodesia/Southern Rhodesia.
And these myths are being used to this very day.
Just one correction, I meant Kenneth P. Vickery.
Black and White in Southern Zambia: The Tonga Plateau Economy and British Imperialism, 1890-1939 (Contributions in Comparative Colonial Studies) (Hardcover), by Kenneth P. Vickery.
Post a Comment
Subscribe to Post Comments [Atom]
<< Home